AP Microeconomics vocab from 5 Steps to a 5 Book
13429986650 | Economics | The study of how people, firms, and societies use their scarce productive resources to best satisfy their unlimited material wants. | 0 | |
13429986651 | Resources | Factors of production, 4 categories: labor, physical capital, land/natural resources, and entrepreneurial ability | 1 | |
13429986652 | Scarcity | The imbalance between limited productive resources and unlimited human wants | 2 | |
13429986653 | Opportunity Cost | The most desirable alternative given up as the result of a decision | 3 | |
13429986654 | Marginal Benefit (MB) | The additional benefit received from the consumption of the next unit of a good or service | 4 | |
13429986655 | Marginal Cost (MC) | The additional cost incurred from the consumption of the next unit of a good or a service | 5 | |
13429986656 | Marginal Analysis | The rational decision maker chooses an action if MB ≥ MC | 6 | |
13429986657 | Law of Increasing Costs | The more of a good that is produced, the greater the opportunity cost of producing the next unit of that good | 7 | |
13429986658 | Absolute Advantage | Exists if a producer can produce more of a good than all other producers | 8 | |
13429986659 | Comparative Advantage | Exists if a producer can produce a good at lower opportunity cost than all other producers | 9 | |
13429986660 | Specialization | When firms focus their resources on production of goods for which they have comparative advantage | 10 | |
13429986661 | Productive Efficiency | Production of maximum output for a given level of technology and resources. All points on the PPF are productively efficient | 11 | |
13429986662 | Allocative Efficiency | Production of the combination of goods and services that provides the most net benefit to society. The optimal quantity of a good is achieved when the MB = MC of the next unit and only occurs at one point on the PPF | 12 | |
13429986663 | Economic Growth | Occurs when an economy's production possibilities increase. This can be a result of more resources, better resources, or improvements in technology. | 13 | |
13429986664 | Market Economy (Capitalism) | An economic system based upon the fundamentals of private property, freedom, self-interest, and prices | 14 | |
13429986665 | Law of Demand | Holding all else equal, when the price of a good rises, consumers decrease their quantity demanded for that good | 15 | |
13429986666 | Absolute prices | The price of a good measured in units of currency | 16 | |
13429986667 | Relative Prices | The number of units of any other good Y that must be sacrificed to acquire good X. Only relative prices matter | 17 | |
13429986668 | Substitution Effect | The change in quantity demanded resulting from a change in the price of one good relative to other goods | 18 | |
13429986669 | Income Effect | The change in quantity demanded that results from a change in the consumer's purchasing power (or real income) | 19 | |
13429986670 | Determinants of Demand | Consumer income, prices of substitute and complementary goods, consumer tastes and preferences, consumer speculation, and number of buyers in the market all influence demand | 20 | |
13429986671 | Normal Goods | A good for which higher income increases demand | 21 | |
13429986672 | Inferior Goods | A good for which higher income decreases demand | 22 | |
13429986673 | Substitute Goods | Two goods are consumer substitutes if they provide essentially the same utility to consumers | 23 | |
13429986674 | Complementary Goods | Two goods are consumer complements if they provide more utility when consumed together than when consumed separately | 24 | |
13429986675 | Law of Supply | Holding all else equal, when the price of a good rises, suppliers increase their quantity supplied for that good | 25 | |
13429986676 | Determinants of Supply | Costs of inputs, technology and productivity, taxes/subsidies, producer speculation, price of other goods that could be produced, and number of sellers all influence supply | 26 | |
13429986677 | Market Equilibrium | Exists at the point where the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded | 27 | |
13429986678 | Shortage | Excess demand; a shortage exists at a market price when the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied | 28 | |
13429986679 | Surplus | Excess supply; exists at a market price when the quantity supplied exceeds the quantity demanded. | 29 | |
13429986680 | Total Welfare | The sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus | 30 | |
13429986681 | Consumer surplus | The difference between your willingness to pay and the price you actually pay. It is the area below the demand curve and above the price | 31 | |
13429986682 | Producer surplus | The difference between the price received and the marginal cost of producing the good. It is the area above the supply curve and under the price | 32 | |
13429986683 | Price elasticity | Ed = (%dQd)/(%dP). Ignore negative sign | 33 | |
13429986684 | Price elastic demand | Ed > 1, meaning consumers are price sensitive | 34 | |
13429986685 | Price inelastic demand | Ed < 1 | 35 | |
13429986686 | Unit elastic demand | Ed = 1 | 36 | |
13429986687 | Perfectly inelastic | Ed = 0, no response to price change | 37 | |
13429986688 | Perfectly elastic | Ed = ∞, infinite change in demand to price change | 38 | |
13429986689 | Determinants of elasticity | Substitutes, cost as percentage of income, and time to adjust to price changes all influence price elasticity | 39 | |
13429986690 | Total Revenue | TR = P * Qd | 40 | |
13429986691 | Total Revenue Test | Total revenue rises with a price increase if demand is price inelastic and falls with a price increase if demand is price elastic | 41 | |
13429986692 | Income Elasticity | Ei = (%dQd good X)/(%d Income) | 42 | |
13429986693 | Luxury | Ei > 1 | 43 | |
13429986694 | Necessity | 0 < Ei < 1 | 44 | |
13429986695 | Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand | Ex,y = (%dQd good X) / (%d Price Y). If Ex,y > 0, goods X and Y are substitutes. If Ex,y < 0, goods X and Y are complementary | 45 | |
13429986696 | Price Elasticity of Supply | Es = (%dQs) / (%dPrice) | 46 | |
13429986697 | Excise Tax | A per unit tax on production results in a vertical shift in the supply curve by the amount of the tax | 47 | |
13429986698 | Incidence of Tax | The proportion of the tax paid by the consumers in the form of a higher price for the taxed good is greater if demand for the good is inelastic and supply is elastic | 48 | |
13429986699 | Dead Weight Loss | The lost net benefit to society caused by a movement away from the competitive market equilibrium | 49 | |
13429986700 | Subsidy | Has opposite effect of an excise tax, as it lowers the marginal cost of production, forcing the supply curve down | 50 | |
13429986701 | Price floor | A legal minimum price below which the product cannot be sold. If a floor is installed at some level above the equilibrium price, it creates a permanent surplus | 51 | |
13429986702 | Price Ceiling | A legal maximum price above which the product cannot be sold. If a floor is installed at some level above the equilibrium price, it creates a permanent shortage | 52 | |
13429986703 | Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility | The marginal utility from consumption of more and more of that item falls over time | 53 | |
13429986704 | Constrained Utility Maximization | For one good, constrained by prices and income, a consumer stops consuming a good when the price paid for the next unit is equal to the marginal benefit received | 54 | |
13429986705 | Utility Maximizing Rule | MUx / Px = MUy/Py or MUx/MUy = Px/Py | 55 | |
13429986706 | Accounting Profit | The difference between total revenue and total explicit costs | 56 | |
13429986707 | Economic Profit | The difference between total revenue and total explicit and implicit costs | 57 | |
13429986708 | Explicit costs | Direct, purchased, out-of-pocket costs paid to resource suppliers provided by the entrepreneur | 58 | |
13429986709 | Implicit costs | Indirect, non-purchased, or opportunity costs of resources provided by the entrepreneur | 59 | |
13429986710 | Short run | A period of time too short to change the size of the plant, but many other, more variable resources can be changed to meet demand | 60 | |
13429986711 | Long Run | A period of time long enough to alter the plant size. New firms can enter the industry and existing firms can liquidate and exit | 61 | |
13429986712 | Production function | The mechanism for combining production resources, with existing technology, into finished goods and services | 62 | |
13429986713 | Fixed inputs | Production inputs that cannot be changed in the short run. Usually this is the plant size or capital | 63 | |
13429986714 | Variable inputs | Production inputs that the firm can adjust in the short run to meet changes in demand for their output. Often this is labor and/or raw materials | 64 | |
13429986715 | Total Product of Labor (TPL) | The total quantity, or total output of a good produced at each quantity of labor employed | 65 | |
13429986716 | Marginal Product of Labor (MPL) | The change in total product resulting from a change in the labor input. MPL = dTPL/dL, or the slope of total product | 66 | |
13429986717 | Average Product of Labor (APL) | Total product divided by labor employed. APL = TPL/L | 67 | |
13429986718 | Total Fixed Costs (TFC) | Costs that do not vary with changes in short-run output. They must be paid even when output is zero. | 68 | |
13429986719 | Total variable costs (TVC) | Costs that change with the level of output. If output is zero, so are TVCs. | 69 | |
13429986720 | Average Fixed Cost (AFC) | AFC = TFC/Q | 70 | |
13429986721 | Average Variable Cost (AVC) | AVC = TVC/Q | 71 | |
13429986722 | Average Total Cost (ATC) | ATC = TC/Q = AFC + AVC | 72 | |
13429986723 | Economies of Scale | The downward part of the LRAC curve where LRAC falls as plan size increases. This is the result of specialization, lower cost of inputs, or other efficiencies of larger scale. | 73 | |
13429986724 | Constant Returns to Scale | Occurs when LRAC is constant over a variety of plant sizes | 74 | |
13429986725 | Diseconomies of Scale | The upward part of the LRAC curve where LRAC rises as plant size increases. This is usually the result of the increased difficulty of managing larger firms, which results in lost efficiency and rising per unit costs. | 75 | |
13429986726 | Perfect competition | Characterized by many small price-taking firms producing a standardized product in an industry in which there are no barriers to entry or exit | 76 | |
13429986727 | Profit Maximizing Rule | All firms maximize profit by producing where MR = MC | 77 | |
13429986728 | Break-even Point | The output where ATC is minimized and economic profit is zero | 78 | |
13429986729 | Shutdown Point | The output where AVC is minimized. If the price falls below this point, the firm chooses to shut down or produce zero units in the short run | 79 | |
13429986730 | Perfectly competitive long-run equilibrium | Occurs when there is no more incentive for firms to enter or exit. P=MR=MC=ATC and profit = 0 | 80 | |
13429986731 | Normal Profit | Another way of saying that firms are earning zero economic profits or a fair rate of return on invested resources | 81 | |
13429986732 | Constant cost industry | Entry (or exit) of firms does not shift the cost curves of firms in the industry | 82 | |
13429986733 | Increasing Cost Industry | Entry of new firms shifts the cost curves for all firms upward | 83 | |
13429986734 | Decreasing Cost industry | Entry of new firms shifts the cost curves for all firms downward | 84 | |
13429986735 | Monopoly | The least competitive market structure, characterized by a single producer, with no close substitutes, barriers to entry, and price making power | 85 | |
13429986736 | Market power | The ability to set the price above the perfectly competitive level | 86 | |
13429986737 | Natural Monopoly | The case where economies of scale are so extensive that it is less costly for one firm to supply the entire range of demand | 87 | |
13429986738 | Monopoly long-run equilibrium | Pm > MR = MC, which is not allocatively efficient and dead weight loss exists. Pm > ATC, which is not productively efficient. Profit > 0 so consumer surplus is transferred to the monopolist as profit | 88 | |
13429986739 | Price discrimination | The practice of selling essentially the same good to different groups of consumers at different prices | 89 | |
13429986740 | Monopolistic competition | A market structure characterized by a few small firms producing a differentiated product with easy entry into the market | 90 | |
13429986741 | Monopolistic competition long-run equilibrium | Pmc < MR = MC and Pmc > minimum ATC so outcome is not efficient, but profit = 0. | 91 | |
13429986742 | Excess Capacity | The difference between the monopolistic competition output Qmc and the output at minimum ATC. Excess capacity is underused plant and equipment | 92 | |
13429986743 | Oligopoly | A very diverse market structure characterized by a small number of interdependent large firms, producing a standardized or differentiated product in a market with a barrier to entry | 93 | |
13429986744 | Four-firm concentration ratio | A measure of industry market power. Sum the market share of the four largest firms and a ratio above 40% is a good indicator of oligopoly | 94 | |
13429986745 | Non-collusive oligopoly | Models where firms are competitive rivals seeking to gain at the expense of their rivals | 95 | |
13429986746 | Collusive oligopoly | Models where firms agree to mutually improve their situation | 96 | |
13429986747 | Cartel | A group of firms that agree not to compete with each other on the basis of price, production, or other competitive dimensions. Cartel members operate as a monopolist to maximize their joint profits | 97 | |
13429986748 | Marginal Revenue Product (MRP) | Measures the value of what the next unit of a resource (e.g., labor) brings to the firm. MRPL = MR x MPL. In a perfectly competitive product market, MRPL = P x MPL. In a monopoly product market, MR < P so MRPm < MRPc. | 98 | |
13429986749 | Marginal Resource Cost (MRC) | Measures the cost the firm incurs from using an additional unit of input. In a perfectly competitive labor market, MRC = Wage. In a monopsony labor market, the MRC > Wage | 99 | |
13429986750 | Profit Maximizing Resource Employment | The firm hires the profit maximizing amount of a resource at the point where MRP = MRC | 100 | |
13429986751 | Demand for Labor | Labor demand for the firm is MRPL curve. The labor demanded for the entire market DL = ∑MRPL of all firms | 101 | |
13429986752 | Derived Demand | Demand for a resource like labor is derived from the demand for the goods produced by the resource | 102 | |
13429986753 | Determinants of Labor Demand | Product demand, productivity, prices of other resources, and complementary resources | 103 | |
13429986754 | Least-Cost Rule | The combination of labor and capital that minimizes total costs for a given production rate. Hire L and K so that MPL / PL = MPK / PK or MPL/MPK = PL/PK | 104 | |
13429986755 | Monopsonist | A firm that has market power in the factor market (a wage-setter) | 105 | |
13429986756 | Private goods | Goods that are both rival and excludable. Only one person can consume the good at a time and consumers who do not pay for the good are excluded from consumption | 106 | |
13429986757 | Public goods | Goods that are both nonrival and nonexcludable. One person's consumption does not prevent another from also consuming that good and if it is provided to some, it is necessarily provided to all, even if they do not pay for that good | 107 | |
13429986758 | Free-Rider Problem | In the case of a public good, some members of the community know that they can consume the public good while others provide for it. This results in a lack of private funding and forces the government to provide it | 108 | |
13429986759 | Spillover benefits | Additional benefits to society not captured by the market demand curve from the production of a good, result in a price that is too high and a market quantity that is too low. Resources are underallocated to the production of this good | 109 | |
13429986760 | Positive externality | Exists when the production of a good creates utility for third parties not directly involved in the consumption of production of the good | 110 | |
13429986761 | Spillover costs | Additional costs to society not captured by the market supply curve from the production of a good, result in a price that is too low and a market quantity that is too high. Resources are overallocated to the production of this good | 111 | |
13429986762 | Negative externality | Exists when the production of a good imposes disutility upon third parties not directly involved in the consumption or production of the good | 112 | |
13429986763 | Marginal Productivity Theory | The philosophy that a citizen should receive a share of economic resources proportional to the marginal revenue product of his or her productivity | 113 | |
13429986764 | Marginal tax rate | The rate paid on the last dollar earned. This is found by taking the ratio of the change in taxes divided by the change in income | 114 |